Where does Debt come From?
However what does our money
really represent and where does it come from? Only once we are able
to answer these questions can we move on to understand why debt is
so ubiquitous in our current economic system.
As the Government looks to cut
funding to Higher Education Institutions, graduates are instead
being asked to pay for the void Messieurs Cameron and Clegg have
left them with. With the possibility of student debt rising to
£40,000, students have been vociferous in their response against
the hikes in tuition fees. The previous article called to students
to make a rational response against the proposals and tackle the
issue by confronting the core problem of debt. But before
addressing this key matter, it is important to understand why we
have debt in the first place.
There is a common saying that
'money makes the world go around', yet it is astounding how little
the general public know about it. We generally see money as a means
by which to purchase commodities, and something readily available
to us from the 'hole in the wall'. However what does our money
really represent and where does it come from? Only once we are able
to answer these questions can we move on to understand why debt is
so ubiquitous in our current economic system.
The roots of our modern
banking system can be traced back to the 17th century, where a
customer would deposit his gold coins (which was state money at the
time) to the goldsmith for safe keeping, and in return the customer
would receive a paper 'bearer receipt' for this. The goldsmiths
would charge the customer a fee for keeping the gold in their
vaults, and upon presentation of the 'bearer receipt', the
goldsmith would have to give the customer their gold.[1]
Rather than going to the bank
to obtain their gold deposits for purchasing goods, customers found
it more convenient to purchase commodities by handing over the
'bearer receipt' to the vendor of the goods so that they could
withdraw the deposits if they wished to do so. This system of
purchasing became quite popular, and so, more people began
depositing their state money with goldsmith, and then trade with
the 'bearer receipt'. As these receipts remained in circulation for
a long time, they eventually became money. Thus, a situation
emerged where two types of money began to exist; 'state money'
being that of gold coins, and 'bank money' consisting of paper
receipts issued by the goldsmiths.[2]
The goldsmiths realized that
with so many people depositing their gold and trading in receipts,
they had large amounts of gold sitting idle in their vaults. They
decided that it would be in their favour to lend this gold to
people of reputable stature at interest, so that they could obtain
some return on their deposits. When lending gold to investors at
interest, the goldsmith had to be cautious on the amount of gold he
was lending. He would have to keep enough gold to meet the requests
of depositors who wanted redemption of their receipts. Naturally,
there would have been instances where customers would make huge
withdrawals in one day, forcing the bank to close its doors to the
public. This would then lead to a lack of confidence in the system,
causing the infamous 'bank run'. The key word here is confidence;
so long as the public believed that they would get their money on
demand, confidence in the system would remain high.
Most of the time, however,
withdrawals would generally be relatively small, and so, banks
could afford to lend most of the deposits in their possession. The
amount of money the bank should keep against the value of receipts
it issued is what is known today as the 'fractional reserve'. Some
argued that this ratio should always be 100%, in which the amount
of gold in its possession would equal the value of receipts it
issued. This meant that the bank would have always been in a
position to meet requests for withdrawals. Others however were
tempted by the lucrative nature of having a reserve as low as 20%,
such that if a bank had £1000 worth of gold, it would keep £200 for
honouring withdrawals, thereby allowing it to lend £800 at
lucrative interest rates.
It later became apparent to
bankers that they didn't have to physically loan out the gold in
their possession, as the receipts they issued equally had the power
to purchase goods. Therefore, supposing a banker had £1000 of gold
in his vault, if he operated on a reserve of 20%, he could print
receipts to the value of £5000, giving £1000 worth of receipts to
depositors, with the remaining £4000 being used for loans. This was
a crucial development, as it gave the banker the power to
'manufacture' money out of nothing, and at little cost. It also
illustrates how the bankers had a firm control on the supply of
money in circulation.
In 1844, Robert Peel passed
the Bank Charter Act which aimed to prevent banks from printing
money in excess of their gold reserves. However, the banks tried to
side-step this piece of legislation by creating the cheque and
account system, which would allow them to retain the power of
creating money. Let us assume there are two customers of a bank, A
and B, each of whom has a zero account balance. A wishes to buy
goods to the value of £100 from B, and so writes him a cheque for
that value. The bank credits customer B with £100, whilst customer
A is in overdraft to the value of £100. In this way, the bank again
has created £100 out of nothing. From this we can see that one
group of customers must always be in debt to an amount that equals
the supply of bank money. Moreover, if A repays his debt by
depositing a cheque of £100 drawn on customer B, then money is
essentially destroyed.[3]
By understanding the evolution
of modern banking, we can appreciate the situation today in which
the Bank of England prints paper money and the commercial banks
create money in the form of electronic credits. Modern day currency
is not associated with a commodity such as gold, but in reality is
just a piece of paper. Thus, we have gone from a situation in which
state currency was in the form of gold and bank currency in the
form of paper, to today where the central bank prints money is in
the form paper and commercial banks create money in the form of
electronic credits. The principle theories, upon which early banks
operated however, remain the same. Banks still operate on the
fractional reserve system, they lend money and profit from lending
through interest, and they have the ability to create money out of
nothing. Furthermore, the amount of bank money in circulation must
balance with amount of customers in debt. As we have illustrated
above that banks create money through debt, repayments of loans are
not in the bank's interest as this destroys money, and a decrease
in money supply leads to recession. Hence, debt must always
exist.
With such an economic model,
the cycle of economic boom and bust cannot be prevented. It is a
fact that we will have periods of a false sense of security leading
to 'economic growth' when money supply is high only for such
periods to be followed by periods of recession in which people
struggle to repay debts ultimately due to a lack of money
supply.
Such an economic model can
have serious consequences, not only to the individual, but also to
small businesses, larger ones, and even nations. The dangers of
such an economic model were highlighted by Thomas Jefferson:
"If the American people ever
allow the banks to control the issuance of their currency, first by
inflation then by deflation, the banks and corporations that will
grow up around them will deprive the people of all property until
their children will wake up homeless on the continent their fathers
occupied. The issuing power of money should be taken from the banks
and restored to Congress and the people to whom it belongs. I
sincerely believe that banking institutions are more dangerous than
standing armies.[4]"
Relating this to the situation
of British students, it should be apparent that merely calling for
the abolishment of planned hikes in tuition fees does not answer
their problem of debt. Even if they manage to have the motion
repealed, they will still be in debt when they graduate, and will
continue to be forced into further debts when they start their
climb on the housing ladder. Having students start their adult
lives with high levels of debt works in favour of the current
economic model, and also helps to understand how debt has become
the norm, and not the exception, in our society. Perhaps the
problems of our current banking system are best summarized by Robert Hemphill:
"We are completely dependant
on the (centralized) commercial banks. Someone has to borrow every
dollar in circulation, cash or credit. If the banks create ample
synthetic money (through the fractional reserve system) we are
prosperous; if not we starve. We are absolutely without a permanent
money system…It is the most important subject intelligent persons
can investigate and reflect upon. It is so important that our
present civilization may collapse unless it becomes widely
understood and the defects remedied very soon. [5]"
When one takes time to reflect
upon the nature of our current banking system, it should become
quite clear that the issue of debt is something which affects us
all. But with students being amongst the most vulnerable in this
economic system, the nature of their response against the hikes is
quite important. Protesting against the hikes, whether performed
peacefully or violently, will not lead to an end in debt. The
ultimate solution to putting an end to the huge sums of personal
debt we all face is to question our current economic model which
essentially functions on the creation of debt. Students should
initiate a public debate by putting our current economic model on
trial against an alternative paradigm which isn't based on debt
creation. By doing so, they will be taking the first steps to help
ease the suffering of many throughout the world who have been
crippled by debt.
Source:
www.islam21c.com
Footnotes:
[1]
Tarek El-Diwany. Travelling
the Wrong Road Patiently. http://www.islamic-finance.com/item132_f.htm.
Viewed on 14th December 2010
[2]
The Problem With Interest.
Tarek El-Diwany. (London:Kreatoc, 2003) pp36-37
[3]
Tarek El Diwany. Why Are We
All in Debt (youtube Video). http://en.wathakker.net/lib_audio/view.php?id=603. Viewed 14th December
2010
[4]
Thomas Jefferson.
Autobiography, Correspondence, Reports, Messages, Addresses and
other Writings. the Writings of Jefferson, vol. 7. 1861, p.
685
[5]
Irving Fisher. 100% Money.
1935, p. Foreward
- Category: